[1]
A. Mitchell Polinsky Law, Economic Analysis of. 7670–7689.
[2]
Alchian, A.A. and Demsetz, H. 1972. Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization. The American Economic Review. 62, 5 (1972).
[3]
An Overview of the Evolution and Enforcement of Antitrust Laws in the European Union and United States: https://www.americanbar.org/groups/young_lawyers/publications/tyl/topics/antitrust/an-overview-the-evolution-and-enforcement-antitrust-laws-the-european-union-and-united-states/.
[4]
Archibald, G.C. Firm, Theory of the. 4719–4729. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95189-5_25.
[5]
Arnsperger, C. and Varoufakis, Y. 2006. What is neoclassical economics? The three axioms responsible for its theoretical oeuvre, practical irrelevance and, thus, discursive power. Panoeconomicus. 53, 1 (2006), 5–18. DOI:https://doi.org/10.2298/PAN0601005A.
[6]
Ayres, I. and Gertner, R. Filling Gaps in Incomplete Contracts: An Economic Theory of Default Rules. The Yale Law Journal. 99, 1, 87–130.
[7]
Baars, G. and Spicer, A. eds. 2017. The corporation: a critical, multi-disciplinary handbook. Cambridge University Press.
[8]
Beckert, J. 2007. The Great Transformation of Embeddedness: Karl Polanyi and the New Economic Sociology. SSRN Electronic Journal. (2007). DOI:https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2465810.
[9]
Black, J. 2013. Reconceiving Financial Markets—From the Economic to the Social. Journal of Corporate Law Studies. 13, 2 (Oct. 2013), 401–442. DOI:https://doi.org/10.5235/14735970.13.2.401.
[10]
Blair, M.M. and Stout, L.A. 1999. A Team Production Theory of Corporate Law. Virginia Law Review. 85, 2 (Mar. 1999).
[11]
Boerger, L. 18AD. Neoclassical Economics. Exploring Economics. (18AD).
[12]
Bolton, P. and Dewatripont, M. 2005. Contract theory. MIT Press.
[13]
Callon, M. 1998. An Essay on Framing and Overflowing: Economic Externalities Revisited by Sociology. The Sociological Review. 46, 1_suppl (May 1998), 244–269.
[14]
Callon, M. 1998. The Embeddedness of Markets in Economics. The Sociological review monograph. 46, (1998).
[15]
Callon, M. 1998. The laws of the markets. Blackwell Publishers/Sociological Review.
[16]
Campbell, D. 2018. The ‘Market’ in the Theory of Regulation. Social & Legal Studies. 27, 5 (Oct. 2018), 545–571. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1177/0964663917730122.
[17]
Cheung, S.N.S. 1983. The Contractual Nature of the Firm. The Journal of Law & Economics. 26, 1 (1983), 1–21.
[18]
CLAASSEN, R. 2016. Externalities as a basis for regulation: a philosophical view. Journal of Institutional Economics. 12, 03 (Sep. 2016), 541–563. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137415000491.
[19]
Claassen, R. and Gerbrandy, A. 2016. Rethinking European Competition Law: From a Consumer Welfare to a Capability Approach. Utrecht Law Review. 12, 1 (Jan. 2016), 1–15. DOI:https://doi.org/10.18352/ulr.321.
[20]
Coase, R.H. 1972. Industrial organization: a proposal for research.
[21]
Coase, R.H. 1990. The firm, the market and the law. University of Chicago Press.
[22]
Coase, R.H. 1990. The firm, the market and the law. University of Chicago Press.
[23]
Coase, R.H. 1990. The firm, the market and the law. University of Chicago Press.
[24]
Coase, R.H. 1990. The firm, the market and the law. University of Chicago Press.
[25]
Coase, R.H. 1974. The Lighthouse in Economics. The Journal of Law & Economics. 17, 2 (1974), 357–376.
[26]
Coase, R.H. 1937. The Nature of the Firm. Economica. 4, 16 (Nov. 1937), 386–405. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x.
[27]
Coase, R.H. 2013. The Problem of Social Cost. The Journal of Law and Economics. 56, 4 (Nov. 2013), 837–877. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1086/674872.
[28]
Cox, R.H.J. and Manton, E. 2012. Revolution justified. Planet Prosperity Foundation.
[29]
Cox, R.H.J. and Manton, E. 2012. Revolution justified. Planet Prosperity Foundation.
[30]
Dahlman, C.J. 1979. The Problem of Externality. The Journal of Law and Economics. 22, 1 (Apr. 1979), 141–162. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1086/466936.
[31]
Danielsen, D. 2015. Corporate Power and Instrumental States: Toward A Critical Reassessment of the Role of Firms, States and Regulation in Global Governance.
[32]
Deakin, S. 2006. ‘Capacitas’: Contract Law and the Institutional Preconditions of a Market Economy. European Review of Contract Law. 2, 3 (Jan. 2006). DOI:https://doi.org/10.1515/ERCL.2006.025.
[33]
Deakin, S. 2006. ‘Capacitas’: Contract Law and the Institutional Preconditions of a Market Economy. European Review of Contract Law. 2, 3 (Jan. 2006). DOI:https://doi.org/10.1515/ERCL.2006.025.
[34]
Deakin, S. et al. 2017. Legal institutionalism: Capitalism and the constitutive role of law. Journal of Comparative Economics. 45, 1 (Feb. 2017), 188–200. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jce.2016.04.005.
[35]
Deakin, S. 2012. The Corporation as Commons: Rethinking Property Rights, Governance and Sustainability in the Business Enterprise. Queen’s Law Journal. 37, (2012), 339–381.
[36]
Denning, S. 25AD. Did Ronald Coase Get Economics Wrong? Forbes. (25AD).
[37]
Diamond, P.A. and Maskin, E. 1979. An Equilibrium Analysis of Search and Breach of Contract, I: Steady States. The Bell Journal of Economics. 10, 1 (Spring 1979). DOI:https://doi.org/10.2307/3003332.
[38]
Dimmelmeier, A. and Heussner, F. 18AD. Institutionalist Economics. Exploring Economics. (18AD).
[39]
Dixit, A.K. 2014. Microeconomics: a very short introduction. Oxford University Press.
[40]
Du Boff, R.B. and Herman, E.S. 2001. Mergers, Concentration, and the Erosion of Democracy. Monthly Review. 53, 1 (2001), 14–29.
[41]
Economics: An Illustrated Timeline - Economic Questions: https://economicquestions.org/history-economics-made-simple/.
[42]
Edelman, L.B. 2004. Rivers of Law and Contested Terrain: A Law and Society Approach to Economic Rationality. Law & Society Review. 38, 2 (2004), 181–198.
[43]
Farber, D. A. 1984. Contract Law and Modern Economic Theory. Northwestern University Law Review. 2 (1984).
[44]
Farber, D. A. 1984. Contract Law and Modern Economic Theory. Northwestern University Law Review. 2 (1984).
[45]
Fink, E.M. 2004. Post-Realism, or the Jurisprudential Logic of Late Capitalism: A Socio-Legal Analysis of the Rise and Diffusion of Law and Economics. Hastings Law Journal. 55, (2004).
[46]
Fligstein, N. 2002. The architecture of markets: an economic sociology of twenty-first-century capitalist societies. Princeton University Press.
[47]
Foss, N.J. 1993. Theories of the firm: contractual and competence perspectives. Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 3, 2 (Jun. 1993), 127–144. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01213830.
[48]
Foss, N.J. 1993. Theories of the firm: contractual and competence perspectives. Journal of Evolutionary Economics. 3, 2 (Jun. 1993), 127–144. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1007/BF01213830.
[49]
Frerichs, S. 2009. The Legal Constitution of Market Society: Probing the Economic Sociology of Law. Economic Sociology – European Electronic Newsletter. 10, 3 (2009), 20–25.
[50]
Fried, C. 2015. Contract as promise: a theory of contractual obligation. Oxford University Press.
[51]
Fried, C. 2015. Contract as promise: a theory of contractual obligation. Oxford University Press.
[52]
Friedman, D.D. 2000. Law’s order: what economics has to do with law and why it matters. Princeton University Press.
[53]
Friedman, D.D. 2000. Law’s order: what economics has to do with law and why it matters. Princeton University Press.
[54]
Galbraith, J.K. 1991. A history of economics: the past as the present. Penguin Books Ltd.
[55]
Ganesh Sitaraman 2018. We must hold capitalism accountable. Elizabeth Warren shows how. Guardian. (Aug. 2018).
[56]
Hale, R.L. 1923. Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State. Political Science Quarterly. 38, 3 (Sep. 1923). DOI:https://doi.org/10.2307/2142367.
[57]
Hart, O. 1989. Economist’s Perspective on the Theory of the Firm, An. Columbia Law Review. (1989).
[58]
Hart, O. and Moore, J. 1988. Incomplete Contracts and Renegotiation. Econometrica. 56, 4 (Jul. 1988). DOI:https://doi.org/10.2307/1912698.
[59]
Hayek, F.A. von 1967. Studies in philosophy, politics and economics. Routledge & Kegan Paul.
[60]
Hodgson, G.M. 1993. Institutional economics: surveying the "old” and the "new”. Metroeconomica. 44, 1 (Feb. 1993), 1–28. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.1993.tb00786.x.
[61]
Hodgson, G.M. 1993. Institutional economics: surveying the ‘old’ and the ‘new’. Metroeconomica. 44, 1 (Feb. 1993), 1–28. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.1993.tb00786.x.
[62]
Hodgson, G.M. 1998. The Approach of Institutional Economics. Journal of Economic Literature. 36, 1 (1998), 166–192.
[63]
Hodgson, G.M. 2000. What Is the Essence of Institutional Economics? Journal of Economic Issues. 34, 2 (2000), 317–329.
[64]
Jensen, M.C. and Meckling, W.H. 1976. Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. Journal of Financial Economics. 3, 4 (Oct. 1976), 305–360. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1016/0304-405X(76)90026-X.
[65]
Kennedy, D. and Michelman, F. 1980. Are Property and Contract Efficient. Hofstra Law Review. 8, 3 (1980), 711–770.
[66]
Lang, A.T.F. 2013. The Legal Construction of Economic Rationalities? Journal of Law and Society. 40, 1 (Mar. 2013), 155–171. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-6478.2013.00617.x.
[67]
Lawson, T. 2015. The nature of the firm and peculiarities of the corporation. Cambridge Journal of Economics. 39, 1 (Jan. 2015), 1–32. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beu046.
[68]
Lawson, T. 2015. The nature of the firm and peculiarities of the corporation. Cambridge Journal of Economics. 39, 1 (Jan. 2015), 1–32. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/beu046.
[69]
Macneil, I. R. 1978. Contracts:  Adjustment of Long-Term Economic Relations under Classical, Neoclassical, and Relational Contract Law. Northwestern University Law Review. 6 (1978).
[70]
Mankiw, N.G. 2015. Principles of economics. Cengage Learning.
[71]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage Learning.
[72]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage Learning.
[73]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage.
[74]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage.
[75]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage.
[76]
Mankiw, N.G. 2018. Principles of economics. Cengage.
[77]
Mirowski, P. 1989. More heat than light: economics as social physics, physics as nature’s economics. Cambridge University Press.
[78]
Mueller, D.C. 2012. The Oxford handbook of capitalism. Oxford University Press.
[79]
My Bookmarks | University of Glasgow: https://glasgow.rl.talis.com/users/36B73502-D222-393E-4346-CBDF597724A0/bookmarks.html.
[80]
Olah, D. The Amazing Arab Scholar Who Beat Adam Smith by Half a Millennium. Evonomics.
[81]
Posner, E.A. 2003. Economic Analysis of Contract Law after Three Decades: Success or Failure. Yale Law Journal. (2003), 829–880.
[82]
Posner, R.A. 1998. Economic analysis of law. Aspen Law & Business.
[83]
Putterman, L.G. and Kroszner, R. 1996. The economic nature of the firm: a reader. Cambridge University Press.
[84]
Putterman, L.G. and Kroszner, R. 1996. The economic nature of the firm: a reader. Cambridge University Press.
[85]
Redmond, W. 2013. Three Modes of Competition in the Marketplace. American Journal of Economics and Sociology. 72, 2 (Apr. 2013), 423–446. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1111/ajes.12011.
[86]
Results for ‘hale coercion’ - Search: https://glasgow.summon.serialssolutions.com/?s.q=hale+coercion&s.cmd=addFacetValueFilters%28ContentType%2CNewspaper+Article%2Ct%7CContentType%2CBook+Review%2Ct%29#!/search?ho=t&fvf=ContentType,Newspaper%20Article,t%7CContentType,Book%20Review,t&l=en-UK&q=hale%20coercion.
[87]
Roncaglia, A. 2005. The Wealth of Ideas: A History of Economic Thought. Cambridge University Press.
[88]
Salomon, M.E. and Arnott, C. 2014. Better Development Decision-making: Applying International Human Rights Law to Neoclassical Economics. Nordic Journal of Human Rights. 32, 1 (Jan. 2014), 44–74. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1080/18918131.2013.878892.
[89]
Samuels, W.J. 1995. The present state of institutional economics. Cambridge Journal of Economics. 19, 4 (Aug. 1995), 569–590. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035331.
[90]
Sanjay reddy and Institute for New Economic Thinking 2015. Externalities and Public Goods: Theory OR Society? (Nov. 2015).
[91]
Shaikh, A. 2016. Capitalism: competition, conflict, crises. Oxford University Press.
[92]
Shavell, S. 2006. On the Writing and the Interpretation of Contracts. The Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization. 22, 2 (Oct. 2006), 289–314. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewj017.
[93]
Shiller, R.J. Speculative Asset Prices (Nobel Prize Lecture).
[94]
Sokol, D.D. et al. eds. 2013. Competition law and development. Stanford Law Books, an imprint of Stanford University Press.
[95]
SpringerLink (Online service) 2018. The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan UK.
[96]
Suchman, M.C. 2003. The Contract as Social Artifact. Law & Society Review. 37, 1 (2003), 91–142.
[97]
Sunstein, C.R. 2000. Behavioral law and economics. Cambridge University Press.
[98]
Swedberg, R. 2003. The Case for an Economic Sociology of Law. Theory and Society. 32, 1 (2003), 1–37.
[99]
Thorsen, D. 2010. The Neoliberal Challenge - What is Neoliberalism. Contemporary Readings in Law and Social Justice. 2, 2 (2010).
[100]
Ventura, A. et al. 2016. Pareto Efficiency, the Coase Theorem, and Externalities: A Critical View. Journal of Economic Issues. 50, 3 (Jul. 2016), 872–895. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1080/00213624.2016.1213595.
[101]
Viaggi, G. Reawakening: From the Origins of Economic Ideas to the Challenges of Our Time’.
[102]
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. Free Press.
[103]
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. Free Press.
[104]
Williamson, O.E. 1985. The economic institutions of capitalism: firms, markets, relational contracting. Free Press.
[105]
20170727. Coase’s theory of the firm. The Economist. (20170727).
[106]
1973. The Fable of the Bees: An Economic Investigation. The Journal of Law and Economics. 16, 1 (Apr. 1973), 11–33. DOI:https://doi.org/10.1086/466753.
[107]
The Problem of Social Cost. The Journal of Law & Economics. 56, 4.